World Library  
Flag as Inappropriate
Email this Article

Coase conjecture

Article Id: WHEBN0015080345
Reproduction Date:

Title: Coase conjecture  
Author: World Heritage Encyclopedia
Language: English
Subject: Ronald Coase, Pacman conjecture, Pricing, Index of economics articles
Collection: Anti-Competitive Behaviour, Monopoly (Economics), Pricing
Publisher: World Heritage Encyclopedia
Publication
Date:
 

Coase conjecture

The Coase conjecture, developed first by Ronald Coase, is an argument in monopoly theory. The conjecture sets up a situation in which a monopolist sells a durable good to a market where resale is impossible and faces consumers who have different valuations. The conjecture proposes that a monopolist that does not know individuals' valuations will have to sell its product at a low price if the monopolist tries to separate consumers by offering different prices in different periods. This is because the monopoly is, in effect, in price competition with itself over several periods and the consumer with the highest valuation, if he is patient enough, can simply wait for the lowest price. Thus the monopolist will have to offer a competitive price in the first period which will be low. The conjecture holds only when there is an infinite time horizon, as otherwise a possible action for the monopolist would be to announce a very high price until the second to last period, and then sell at the static monopoly price in the last period. The monopolist could avoid this problem by committing to a stable linear pricing strategy or adopting other business strategies.[1]

Contents

  • Simple two-consumer model 1
  • n consumers 2
  • See also 3
  • References 4
  • Further reading 5

Simple two-consumer model

Imagine there are consumers, called X and Y with valuations of good with x and y respectively. The valuations are such as x. The monopoly cannot directly identify individual consumers but it knows that there are 2 different valuations of a good. The good being sold is durable so that once a consumer buys it, he or she will still have it in all subsequent periods. This means that after the monopolist has sold to all consumers, there can be no further sales. Also assume that production is such that average cost and marginal cost are both equal to zero.

The monopolist could try to charge at a price = y in the first period and then in the second period price =x , hence price discriminating. This will not result in consumer Y buying in the first period because, by waiting, she could get price equal to x. To make consumer Y indifferent between buying in the first period or the second period, the monopolist will have to charge a price of price = dx +(1-d)y where d is a discount factor between 0 and 1. This price is such as dx + (1-d)y < y.

Hence by waiting, Y forces the monopolist to compete on price with its future self.

n consumers

Imagine there are n consumers with valuations ranging from y to a valuation just above zero. The monopolist will want to sell to the consumer with the lowest valuation. This is because production is costless and by charging a price just above zero it still makes a profit. Hence to separate the consumers, the monopoly will charge first consumer (1-d^n)y where n is the number of consumers. If the discount factor is high enough this price will be close to zero. Hence the conjecture is proved.

See also

References

  1. ^ http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=496175 [Orbach (2004)

Further reading

  1. Coase, Ronald. "Durability and Monopoly" in Journal of Law and Economics, vol. 15(1), pp. 143–49, 1972.
  2. Orbach, Barak. "The Durapolist Puzzle: Monopoly Power in Durable-Goods Market" in Yale Journal on Regulation, vol. 21(1), pp. 67–118, 2004.
This article was sourced from Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License; additional terms may apply. World Heritage Encyclopedia content is assembled from numerous content providers, Open Access Publishing, and in compliance with The Fair Access to Science and Technology Research Act (FASTR), Wikimedia Foundation, Inc., Public Library of Science, The Encyclopedia of Life, Open Book Publishers (OBP), PubMed, U.S. National Library of Medicine, National Center for Biotechnology Information, U.S. National Library of Medicine, National Institutes of Health (NIH), U.S. Department of Health & Human Services, and USA.gov, which sources content from all federal, state, local, tribal, and territorial government publication portals (.gov, .mil, .edu). Funding for USA.gov and content contributors is made possible from the U.S. Congress, E-Government Act of 2002.
 
Crowd sourced content that is contributed to World Heritage Encyclopedia is peer reviewed and edited by our editorial staff to ensure quality scholarly research articles.
 
By using this site, you agree to the Terms of Use and Privacy Policy. World Heritage Encyclopedia™ is a registered trademark of the World Public Library Association, a non-profit organization.
 


Copyright © World Library Foundation. All rights reserved. eBooks from Project Gutenberg are sponsored by the World Library Foundation,
a 501c(4) Member's Support Non-Profit Organization, and is NOT affiliated with any governmental agency or department.